Gabriel
Zucman and his colleagues are advocating a progressive wealth tax as a
solution to global inequality, one that rethinks both evasion and the
goals of taxation.
Illustration by Claire Merchlinsky; Source Photograph by Bruno Arbesu / REA / Redux
To trace
the progress of the wealth tax from a fringe academic idea to the
center of the Democratic Presidential primary, it is helpful to begin a
bit off-center. On September 15, 2008, the day that Lehman Brothers
filed for bankruptcy, a twenty-one-year-old student of Thomas Piketty,
Gabriel Zucman, started work as a trainee economic analyst in the
offices of a Paris brokerage house called Exane. Zucman felt obviously
underequipped for the task before him: to write memos to the brokerage
house’s clients and traders helping to explain why the very durable and
minutely engineered global financial system appeared to be on the verge
of collapse. Poring over some of the data he was given, which concerned
the international flows of investments, Zucman noticed some strange
patterns. The amount of money that had been moving through a handful of
very small economies (Luxembourg, the Cayman Islands, the tiny Channel
Islands of Jersey and Guernsey) was staggering. “Hundreds of billions of
dollars,” Zucman recalled recently, making the “B” in “billions”
especially emphatic. Eventually, he would calculate that half of all
foreign direct investment—half of the risk-seeking bets, placed from
overseas in India, China, Brazil, and Silicon Valley, and of the
safety-seeking investments, placed in the United States and Europe and
stock indexes—was moving through offshore hubs like these.
Before
the financial crisis, the rise of offshore tax havens hadn’t been
ignored—one element of the Enron scandal of 2001, for instance, was the
eight hundred and eighty-one overseas subsidiaries the company had
created, which had helped it avoid paying federal taxes for three
years—but those stories took place within a more confined and more
frankly moral framework: it was a cat-and-mouse plot, about the mobility
of wealth, and the fruitless efforts to pursue it. Zucman’s intuition
was that these arrangements did not describe a moral or a legal drama
but a macroeconomic one. That much wealth, poorly documented or
regulated, might have helped to destabilize the global economy. It also
seemed that, if economists were not attuned to the amount of wealth
stored in offshore havens, they might also have missed the extent of
global inequality, since it was billionaires who stored money in the
Cayman Islands, not retirees. “You know, the way we study inequality is
we use survey data, state-tax data,” Zucman told me, “and that’s not
going to capture these Swiss bank accounts.” After half a year at Exane,
Zucman was back in graduate school, working with Piketty on the study
of wealth inequality in the United States and Europe that became
Piketty’s landmark book, from 2013, “Capital in the Twenty-First Century,” as well as on his own fixation—on how big the island-shaped loopholes in the global economy would turn out to be.
For
the next several years, Zucman followed two tracks. The first led
deeper into the mists of offshore banking systems. In obscure monthly
reports of the Swiss central bank he discovered that foreigners held
$2.5 trillion in wealth there (Zucman would eventually calculate that
$7.6 trillion, or eight per cent of global household wealth, was held in
tax havens, three-quarters of it undeclared) and that these immense
sums were mostly being diverted to mutual funds incorporated in
Luxembourg, the Cayman Islands, and Ireland. The second track—the work
he did first with Piketty and then with the Piketty collaborator and
Berkeley economist Emmanuel Saez—mapped the acceleration of inequality
around the world and in the United States. The American story was of a
snowball effect, as Zucman described it, in which the very high top
incomes of the nineteen-eighties and nineties were saved and invested,
“and that creates a spiral which is potentially very powerful and leads
to very, very high rates of wealth inequality.” The two stories were in
fact one. The concentration of wealth in secretive tax havens was an
expression of the broader wealth imbalance—the laissez-faire spirit of
the Reagan era working its way through the country and then the world.
“One thing that became clear in my mind when I did the study of the U.S.
wealth inequality is how hard it is to stop the rise of wealth
inequality if you don’t have progressive taxation and, in particular,
progressive wealth taxation,” Zucman told me. Without it, the snowball
just keeps growing.
This work took place during Obama’s
Presidency, a period in which, a bit paradoxically, the global populist
reaction to accumulated wealth was consolidating even as liberal
institutions, belatedly, began to get a handle on the problem. In 2010,
early in Zucman’s doctoral work, Congress had passed the Foreign Account
Tax Compliance Act (FATCA), which required tax
havens to share banking information with the United States or suffer
significant economic sanctions. The program worked, and, by the middle
of the decade, European regulators had compelled tax havens to share the
same information with them. “That actually had a very big impact on my
thinking, because it showed that new forms of international coöperation
can emerge very quickly,” Zucman told me. “In particular, sometimes we
have this view that, ‘Oh, we can’t do anything about tax havens.
Countries are entitled to their own laws, and, if they want to have a
zero-per-cent corporate-tax rate of bank secrecy, that’s their own
right.’ ” But FATCA had demonstrated that tax
havens were not autonomous zones. “At the beginning of my Ph.D.,
whenever I or N.G.O.s would talk about having some automatic exchange of
banking information, policymakers would
say, ‘Oh, that’s a pipe dream.’ And so I witnessed the transition from
pipe dream to, now everybody does it.” He went on, “It can happen very
fast.”
As WikiLeaks oriented international relations around a
central tension, between transparency and secrecy, similar themes and
patterns were emerging in the area of wealth. To parse them required the
tools of an investigative journalist, of discovery and cajoling. Zucman
is an economist, but he also had some of the qualities—youth and
fervency—that investigative reporters often have, and that made him
someone people would go to when they thought something was very wrong. A
leaked trove of foreign wealth data from the Swiss subsidiary of the
banking giant H.S.B.C. made its way to various national tax authorities,
and Scandinavian government officials shared it with Danish and
Norweigan academics who were collaborating with Zucman. There were
limits to what he could see in the H.S.B.C. trove, but it provided a
suggestion of how much wealth from Scandinavian countries was being
stored away in offshore hubs like Switzerland. In 2015, when the Panama
Papers leaked, detailing the evasion efforts of the law firm Mossack
Fonseca, it was possible to see the business of tax evasion in
action—the lawyers, the pitch decks, the business analysts. Shrouding
fortunes was the work of meticulous professionals; when Zucman and
colleagues traced this wealth through tax shelters, they found it often
was finally invested in ordinary stocks and bonds. “It was very
mundane,” Zucman said.
Gradually,
Zucman came to see tax evasion differently. “It’s not a psychological
thing,” he said. There was a market. The key player wasn’t the
billionaire, but the bankers and lawyers who Zucman came to think of as
the tax-evasion industry. The professionals in this industry had bosses,
and partners or shareholders; they worked within a regulated system.
“If you have banks that feel that they are too big to indict then they
will continue to commit some form of financial crimes,” Zucman said.
“They will budget costs for fines.” In 2009, tax havens seemed like
black holes, sucking out so much wealth that it warped the global
economy. By 2019, they seemed dependent on the continued dormancy of the
great liberal apparatus of international banking regulation, which
could be quickly revived. “And the U.S.,” Zucman said, “you know, if
there is a U.S. President that is serious about fighting global
oligarchy, he or she has a ton of power.”
Zucman
works in a small, spare office next door to Saez’s, on the sixth floor
of Evans Hall at U.C. Berkeley. The cinder-block walls are undecorated,
and the only personal touch I could see, when we met there a few weeks
ago, was a small espresso machine. Zucman is fair-skinned, with round
cheeks, light brown hair, and a longish nose, and he was wearing a black
V-neck T-shirt and jeans. (The next morning, when we met again, he
would be wearing a different black V-neck T-shirt and a different pair
of jeans.) The scene seemed a bit unadorned for someone who had, this
year, been named by Prospect magazine, in the U.K., as
one of the fifty most influential thinkers on the planet. He speaks
with a French accent and has an outsider’s sweeping, offhand way of
talking. For all of Piketty’s fame—and his own, and Saez’s—Zucman
mentioned several times that the economics profession had been slow to
recognize inequality as a legitimate topic. He still seemed to have the
outlook of a less powerful person than he now is.
Saez and Zucman have written a book, published this month, called “The Triumph of Injustice,”
which assembles their research into a policy plan. (Its subtitle is the
instruction-manual-like “How the Rich Dodge Taxes and How to Make Them
Pay.”) One way to understand the book is as marking a new phase in the
project that Piketty, Saez, and Zucman share. Having done more than just
about any other economists to describe the powerful effect that
accumulated wealth has on global inequality, they are now advocating for
a solution: a highly progressive annual tax on wealth, an idea that has
been adopted by Elizabeth Warren and Bernie Sanders. Zucman is the
junior partner in the enterprise, but he has also been its chief
propagandist, duelling on Twitter with economists who raise objections
or philosophical gripes, and so the wealth-tax cause has come to reflect
some of his own attributes: his tremendous explanatory power, his
comfort with being an outsider to the establishment, and his great
optimism in what government can know and do about the concentration of
wealth.
A
few weeks ago, Saez and Zucman flew to Washington for a pair of panels
at the Brookings Institution presenting their ideas—one closed to
reporters, and the other open to them—and at the open session Zucman
gave a ten-minute presentation of the book, which, with admirable
concision, boiled the essential story of wealth and the tax code down to
two slides. The first displayed the results of their study of the
aggregate burden of all federal, state, and local taxes after the 2017
Trump tax cuts, which concluded that the United States no longer has a
progressive tax system—statistically, the Trump cuts dealt it a death
blow. Most Americans now pay about the same portion of their income to
the government (the upper-middle class pays very slightly more), and the
wealthiest pay less. The slide is titled “A Giant Flat Tax Which Is Regressive at the Top End.”
To explain how this could be, Zucman likes to use the example of Warren Buffett. Forbes
had estimated Buffett’s wealth to be sixty billion dollars, which
suggested that his wealth was growing by about three billion dollars per
year. But Buffett reported to the I.R.S. capital gains of about ten
million—based on his sales of some shares in his own company, Berkshire
Hathaway. For many years, Buffett has been pointing out that his tax
rate is too low—the line has often been that he pays a lower effective
rate than his secretary—and urging politicians to turn the screws a bit
tighter on the ultra-wealthy. In response, Barack Obama proposed the
Buffett Rule, a principle adopted by Hillary Clinton, in which people
making more than a million dollars a year would have a minimum federal
tax rate of thirty per cent. As of a couple of years ago, this was the
frontier of mainstream Democratic tax policy, but, to Zucman, it was
outlandishly inadequate. Raising the rate on the ten million dollars
that was accessible to the I.R.S. made no statistical difference at all.
The issue was the $59,990,000,000 that they could not touch. Apply the
Buffett Rule, don’t apply the Buffett Rule; it didn’t much matter.
“Functionally, his tax rate is zero per cent,” Zucman said.
The
second chart examines the share of wealth held by the Forbes 400, which
has mushroomed from one per cent of total wealth, at the outset of the
Reagan era, to well over three per cent today. Had Warren’s wealth tax
been in place all along, the Forbes 400’s share would now be about two
per cent. Zucman and Saez propose a stricter wealth tax (ten per cent
annually), which they say would have held the Forbes 400’s share
constant, around one per cent. If you wanted something like the more
equal pre-Reagan America for which Democratic politicians often grow
nostalgic, they suggest, it would take a tax like that.
At the end
of last year, Saez got an e-mail from Bharat Ramamurti, a longtime
economic policy adviser of Elizabeth Warren’s, who said that Warren was
interested in proposing a tax on wealth in some form. Zucman and Saez
created a spreadsheet, using their own estimates of wealth, that allowed
the Warren campaign to play around with different thresholds and rates
for the tax. At first, Ramamurti sketched out a plan that taxed fortunes
of twenty million dollars or more at one per cent. But in Saez and
Zucman's analysis—on the spreadsheet—wealth was so concentrated at the
highest end that a more radically progressive tax, one which targeted a
relatively small number households, could still generate trillions in
revenue. Eventually, the Warren campaign settled on a plan that would
tax fortunes over fifty million dollars at two per cent annually, and
those over one billion at three per cent, which Saez and Zucman
estimated would raise the astonishing sum of $2.75 trillion over the
course of ten years. (The entire revenue of the federal government, in
the current budget year, is $3.4 trillion.) To Zucman, the choice had
the added effect of averting a political problem that had bedevilled
European wealth taxes, which tended to start with much smaller fortunes.
“Above fifty million, you can’t really argue that these people can’t
afford to pay,” Zucman told me.
Something quietly revolutionary
was happening in these conversations, inJanuary, between Ramamurti and
the Berkeley economists, and between Ramamurti and his boss. For
Democratic politicians and policymakers, taxes have generally served as a
tool, to fund a program that they believe the people want. When Barack
Obama proposed a broad expansion of public health insurance, his
advisers developed an intricate, progressive system of taxes to pay for
it, but the rates and thresholds for those taxes had been determined by
the cost of the program. Ramamurti and Warren wanted to maximize
revenue, and they also wanted to reduce inequality, which meant that
they wanted a way to make the wealthy give up more of their fortunes. It
wasn’t an ideological change so much as a conceptual one—about how
pervasive and controlling the effects of inequality are. Taxing wealth
to limit fortunes became a goal in itself.
Elizabeth Warren wasn’t
the first candidate to consider tackling American wealth in this way.
During the 2016 Presidential primaries, Zucman and Saez had an extended
conversation with Warren Gunnels, Bernie Sanders’s longtime economic
adviser, after Sanders had expressed interest in the idea of a wealth
tax. The Berkeley economists scored various versions of the plan,
estimating the revenue and economic effects, and eventually Gunnels
brought a proposal to Sanders and the campaign. The reaction among his
advisers was mixed, and, among the many other policy ideas the Sanders
campaign was considering, this one simply drifted away. Sanders was
already asking Americans to dream of a socialist society like Denmark’s
or Sweden’s, and the wealth tax, which had not succeeded even in Europe,
might have seemed especially exotic, and likely to trigger another
round of denunciations in the American press.
After Hillary
Clinton won the Democratic Presidential nomination, her advisers also
spent several weeks considering whether to propose a wealth tax. As a
matter of framing, one of her advisers explained to me, “There’s huge
merit in the wealth tax—it does bring into sharp focus the inequity in
our tax code as it relates to how you
treat taxing income to wealth.” The campaign’s policy officials would
evaluate how prone it might be to legal challenges, or to the wealthy
avoiding or evading it—but it had an intuitive appeal. Because of the
concentrations of wealth, the adviser said, “the sheer amount of money
you can raise off a wealth tax is staggering.” Clinton herself was
intrigued by the idea, and legal experts prepared memos about its
constitutional viability, while Saez and Zucman helped Clinton’s tax
advisers measure the revenue and economic impacts. But, as with the
Sanders campaign, it was never formally proposed. The adviser went on,
“It was a pretty exotic proposal. Given the way the election was shaping
up, it didn’t seem like the proposal was going to alter the overarching
narrative of the race. The reason I keep coming back to is inertia.”
But
in 2016 not even the socialists had made the conceptual leap: that a
wealth tax could have political appeal separate from, even exceeding,
the appeal of the programs it funded. In September, eight months after
Warren formally announced her proposal, Sanders introduced a wealth tax
that was more extreme still: it starts at a one-per-cent marginal annual
rate for households worth more than thirty-two million, and increases
steeply, to eight per cent, on households worth more than ten billion.
“What we are trying to do,” Sanders told reporters in September, “is
demand and implement a policy which significantly reduces income and
wealth inequality in America by telling the wealthiest families in this
country they cannot have so much wealth.”
As a political matter,
those eight months will be hard for Sanders to make up. The tax itself
is now Warren’s signature proposal, and she has refined her campaign
message around it. At rallies, she asks the crowd how many people own
their own homes, and, once hands are in the air, points out that most
Americans already pay a wealth tax on their biggest asset, they just
call it a property tax. (“Great line,” the Clinton adviser told me. “We
didn’t have that.”) “Your first fifty million is free and clear,” Warren
likes to say on the campaign trail. “But your fifty millionth and first
dollar, you gotta pitch in two cents, and two cents for every dollar
after that.” By the time Warren held a rally before the brilliant
edifice of the Washington Square arch last month, the crowds had begun
to anticipate the line, and, as her speech wound toward the wealth tax,
they chanted back at her, “Two cents! Two cents!” In 2016, Donald Trump
would test out new lines at his rallies, little lures dropped into the
depths of the crowd. Was there a bite? “Build the wall” and “Lock her
up” came back at him, and eventually they became the substance of the
campaign. Shout a slogan back to a candidate, and you have explained the
campaign to itself.
The
real resonance between Zucman and Saez’s proposals and the Presidential
campaign of Elizabeth Warren, the champion of the Consumer Financial
Protection Bureau, may be in their shared optimism about what the modern
American administrative state can accomplish. When I asked William
Gale, the co-director of the Urban-Brookings Tax Policy Center, what
distinguished Saez and Zucman from the center-left policymakers who had
preceded them, he mentioned two elements. First, he said, they wanted
steeper taxes on the wealthy than even most progressives in
Washington—they were left, not center-left. The second difference, Gale
said, was more pronounced. “What I would describe as the previous
center-left consensus is that we ought to raise taxes on the very rich,
but that’s really hard to do,” Gale said. “Saez and Zucman come in and
say, ‘In fact, it’s quite possible; it’s just a matter of enforcement
and getting the taxes right—pushing on both fronts.’ Their policy
optimism is very different from the conversations that people had in the
Obama Administration, where it was often about how the wealthy had
these tax-avoidance strategies, these armies of lawyers, that the
administrative problems were extreme.”
As Saez and Zucman’s ideas
moved to Washington, they met points of resistance, small and big. Jason
Furman, who chaired President Obama’s Council of Economic Advisers,
recently suggested on Twitter that the rich paid slightly more in taxes
than Zucman and Saez’s graphs suggested. But the broader critiques took
aim at their administrative optimism. Since the spring, the former
Treasury Secretary Larry Summers and his colleague Natasha Sarin, a law
professor at the University of Pennsylvania, have been arguing that
Zucman and Saez have radically overestimated how much revenue a wealth
tax would generate, and that the more realistic return, based on what
the I.R.S. had been able to recoup from the estate tax, might be as
little as one-eighth of their projections. Sarin told me, “The
excitement around the Warren proposal is that, by taxing seventy-five
thousand households and imposing a relatively minor additional tax
burden on them, we can pay for just about everything we want. If that
sounds a little unbelievable, I think that’s because it is a little
unbelievable.”
Zucman and Saez published a full response in June,
pointing out that, in several European countries that had tried a wealth
tax, as well as Colombia, the average avoidance rate was about fifteen
per cent; Summers and Sarin, they argued, assumed tax-avoidance rates of
between eighty and ninety per cent.
“They start from the premise that the rich cannot be taxed, to arrive
at the conclusion that a tax on the rich would not collect much,” Zucman
and Saez wrote. Their more colloquial argument was that there was
nothing mysterious about wealth. Seventy per cent of the wealth of the
top 0.1 per cent, Zucman argued, was in the form of stocks, bonds, and
real estate—it was easily valued. More portable forms of wealth, like
art or jewelry, could be assessed through insurance estimates. The
trickiest form of wealth for tax authorities to value is privately held
businesses; Saez and Zucman propose in their book that the I.R.S. could
make an assessment, and if anyone disagreed they could simply transfer
two per cent of their shares in the business to the government, which
would then sell them at auction. Zucman’s deeper theory seemed to be
that no strong wealth tax had ever been tried. The European models had
very low thresholds (often starting around a million dollars), which
made them vulnerable to political attack and legislative exemptions.
Enforcement was often nonexistent. The largest economy to tax wealth in
recent years is France’s, and that levy, Zucman pointed out, relied on
self-reporting. “There was a box on the return for wealth, and you wrote
a number in the box. That was all.”
Liberals have been agitating,
for many years, for an end to the Reagan regime. Now, in Elizabeth
Warren, the Democrats have a leading Presidential candidate who intends
to unwind that era, and the question—the anxiety—is about how much might
come undone. Natasha Sarin, Summers’s co-author, told me, “There’s
another conceptual point that I find interesting. Bill Clinton, when he
was running for President, said the world would be better if there were
more millionaires. I was kind of stunned when I heard Bernie Sanders say
that billionaires should not exist. There is something about that view
that seems deeply alien to what many progressives, I think, believe.
And, economically, I worry, it is deeply inefficient.” Zucman, by
contrast, said at the Brookings conference that Piketty’s next book, due
out next spring, would advocate a wealth tax of ninety per cent for
billionaires. “Really,” Zucman told me, “you could abolish billionaires
if you wanted to.”
From Zucman’s office window in Berkeley, it is
possible to see clear across the bay to San Francisco, where the
escalating forces of inequality had sent housing prices sky-high and
pushed working-class people to the periphery of urban life, as they had
in Paris. The formative political event in Zucman’s life was the 2002
French Presidential election, when he was fifteen, in which the
nationalist Jean-Marie Le Pen won nearly five million votes in the first
round, making it into the runoff, in part because of the sense that all
of the gains of society were being hoarded by élites.
“You know,”
Zucman said, “when you have the fall of the U.S.S.R., the fall of the
Berlin Wall, some people say it’s the triumph of the free-market
economy, the end of history, you won’t do better than that. And,
especially now, in a globalized, integrated world, there’s no viable
progressive platform that’s possible. And the left became discouraged,
as it does—you know, ‘This is all a messy failure. It’s game over,’ ”
Zucman said. “And now, thirty years later, people are realizing that
there are all kinds of contradictions in the way our economies work, and
we can do better.” The United States is only four per cent of the
global population, he went on, but much of the rest of the world had
remade itself in our image thirty years ago, and—if a progressive
administration in Washington could implement a wealth tax, and
strengthen international coöperation for higher corporate tax rates
against tax evasion and offshore havens—maybe it would do so again. “You
could change the U.S., but you could also change the world,” Zucman
said. “Actually, you could be much more radical.”
You will need to use IRS Form 2210 to show that your estimated tax payment is due because of income during a specific time of the year.
ReplyDeletetax specialist in the UK